Thursday, June 9, 2022

Climate finance emperor update

I wrote a review of Stuart Kirk's climate finance speech, which among other things criticized the Dutch Central Bank for putting fingers on the scale in order to make "climate financial risk" look bigger than it is. 

Remember where we are. Here we are not talking about the fantasy that in the next 5 years or so, on the scale of actual bank investments and regulatory horizon, some physical "climate" event will destroy the financial system. We are talking about "transition risk," the chance that our legislators take such extreme action that their carbon policies cause a financial meltdown of systemic proportions. And here, whether a carbon tax could do that.  

Robert Vermeulen of the Dutch Central Bank wrote (in personal capacity, and with extraordinary politeness given the circumstances) to defend their calculations:  

In the Dutch Central Bank scenario Kirk refers to we model the impact of a US$ 100 increase in the carbon price. On whether this is low, high or outrageous we can debate, but if fully passed on to consumers it would make a round trip Amsterdam – New York US$ 200 more expensive.

 The GDP numbers in the table need to be interpreted as relative to the baseline. So, let us assume a baseline GDP growth of 2% per year. Suppose the economy has size 100 in year 0, then the size of the economy is 110 in year 5. So, this baseline economy has a GDP level of 102 in year 1, 104 in year 2, etcetera. Since the scenario needs to be read as relative to the baseline, the GDP level in the scenario is 100.7 in year 1, 100.8 in year 2, 103.2 in year 3, 106.7 in year 4 and 109.5 in year 5. So, the carbon price we model by no means destroys the economy.


With respect to the interest rate shock, this variable is not assumed but follows endogenously from the model. Note that the long-term interest rate increases by 1 percentage point. As the economy grows slower compared to the baseline, the interest rate converges again to the baseline interest rate and is about equal to it in year 5. To put things into perspective, the US 10-year gov’t bond yield increased from 1.72% on March 1st to 3.12% on May 6th this year. Since a carbon price has a very similar effect on fossil fuel energy prices, the increase in long-term interest rates is not something strange and fully in line with what we observed this year.

The main point "the interest rate shock...is not assumed but follows endogenously from the model" Kirk is not correct  in alleging that the high interest rates are a separate assumption plugged in to the model to make GDP fall. 

I have not read the appendix, nor studied the model. However, this being a blog, that won't stop me from a few speculations. 

I am still a little bit puzzled. That a 2% of GDP tax increase should lower GDP makes a lot of sense, as it adds distortions (not counting externalities) to the economy. But real interest rates usually fall in recessions. Perhaps this is a nominal interest rate rise? 

It is also puzzling that a carbon tax is so damaging. In response I needled Robert a bit: Why don't you simulate a decline in Europe's already prodigious fuel taxes? If a rise in the carbon tax lowers GDP this much, a decline in fuel taxes should raise GDP and lower interest rates by similar amounts! 

In response to a few queries from me, Robert adds: 

Please note that we investigate tail risk scenarios and how banks would be affected in case of a sharp increase in carbon prices. In case the policymaker wants to meet the Paris Agreement carbon emission targets we would argue that you ideally present companies with a predictable policy path until 2050. This allows gradual adjustment in the economy, but it requires action soon. However, when governments wait too long and still want to meet the emission targets the economy will receive a bigger shock. 

This is interesting. I presume this means the economic model has very large "adjustment costs." Usually taxes have a "level effect" so the speed of implementation doesn't matter that much. Kirk might have a thing to say about a model in which putting in the carbon tax suddenly has much larger effect than spreading it over a few years.  

Perhaps interesting, in the study we also analyze the effects of technological shocks which make solar power much cheaper and easier to store. Basically this is a deflationary price shock and due to the adjustments in the economy it still leads to some temporary lower GDP growth relative to the baseline growth. In this case you indeed see interest rate decreases because the shock of the source is deflationary, i.e. energy becomes cheaper.

No matter what you do GDP goes down? Usually cost-reducing supply shocks are good for GDP. It seems that this model has a very strong Phillips curve, so that lower inflation (which we now all might think of as a good thing) lowers GDP? Good thing our ancestors who built power plants, highways, and dikes, didn't think that supply improvements lower GDP! The last comment leads to my question whether we're looking at real vs. nominal interest rates.   

Saving the best for last: 

 Please note that carbon price increases, at least of the magnitude we modeled, should not lead to financial crises. For the Dutch economy a US$100 carbon price increase amount to a little less than 2% of Dutch GDP at face value. We modeled it as a quota (e.g. similar to OPEC production limits), so the benefits of the higher prices fall on to the fossil fuel producers. In case you would model it as a tax levied by the governments and would assume that the tax is redistributed e.g. as a decrease in the VAT, you would find (much) smaller GDP impacts. Therefore, with appropriate policies you can ideally achieve simultaneously lower carbon emissions and minimize negative short-term impacts on the economy. 

"Carbon price increases, at least of the [big] magnitude we modeled, should not lead to financial crises." Well, the game is up right there. As for the topic of Kirk's whole speech, is there a financial system risk from climate, or is this all a smokescreen to get central banks to de-fund fossil fuels where legislators will not go, the game is up. (And, I would add, it is even more contradictory for regulators to say they have to step in to de fund fossil fuels before legislators impose the big carbon tax because legislators will never impose the big carbon tax.) 

The last part is important as we think about the actual issue: What you do with  carbon tax revenue matters a lot to its impact on its economic effect. If the carbon tax revenue is used to offset other distorting taxes,  I can easily imagine that GDP rises, a win-win. There are other taxes with far higher marginal rates and far worse distortions. 

We are of course witnessing an experimental version of the calculation, courtesy of Vladimir Putin. Others such as Ben Moll are making more microeconomic calculations that the effect of this large and sudden price hike and quantity reduction will be much smaller. We shall see. We shall also see if there is any stress at all on the banking system as a result of higher oil prices. For now, higher prices are causing dramatic increases in profits of legacy oil, not the collapse that climate financial risk advocates predicted. Econ 101 works.  But it is worth pointing out that the carbon tax and "Putin's price hike" are economically identical, so experience of one can inform the other, and complaining about one is a bit silly if one enthusiastically endorses the other. 



15 comments:

  1. If the government thinks "no matter what you do GDP goes down", perhaps the government should just do nothing? Would that be so hard?

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Just keeping government spending at current levels for next 10 years would squeeze out lots of misallocations of capital.

      Delete
  2. I actually do wish we had studied a lot more history and politics especially of wars in economics courses. Your statement is correct that the economics of the tax and Putin's tax hike are identical, but it doesn't have to be correct. We could as a discipline study war more explicitly and model what I assume are overwhelmingly large carbon footprints etc. If we looked back and saw giant carbon footprints attributable to wars and saw they were the first order magnitude of the last couple of centuries, that would be a greatly interesting spin to all the debates.

    ReplyDelete
  3. This comment has been removed by the author.

    ReplyDelete
  4. This comment has been removed by the author.

    ReplyDelete
  5. "But it is worth pointing out that the carbon tax and "Putin's price hike" are economically identical, so experience of one can inform the other, and complaining about one is a bit silly if one enthusiastically endorses the other. "

    One could easily object that in the carbon tax we can get the revenues and rebate them to reduce other taxes. Whereas with Putin all the money is going to oil and natural gas producers. Admittedly this is a somewhat redistributive argument but one could make the case that the later will result in a very different future scenario (more oil and natural gas, and hence higher emissions, rather than reduced future emissions) which we don't like. In short, they may the same in some static view, but not once we consider future dynamics.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. The other objection I'd think of to the same argument: gas demand is famously more elastic in the long term, and carbon taxes proposals that I've heard have a ramp-up period, so wouldn't a sudden shock be much worse?

      Delete
  6. Does anyone really believe carbon tax revenue will be remitted by reductions in other taxes?

    ReplyDelete
  7. As I recovered from Covid I watched American daytime TV in almost lethal doses. "Infantilize" is my new watchword. It is everywhere. The bankers for instance still think that fractional reserve banking is a good idea. Like the Easter bunny. It won't work in a lower energy return on energy invested environment. The abstractions and models are reality free. They need geologists on board.

    ReplyDelete
  8. The inflation is created by too much demand and not enough production. Wages haven’t gone up enough with inflation. We aren’t in a wage inflation spiral, you hopeless doomer.

    ReplyDelete
  9. Florian HabermacherJune 13, 2022 at 2:24 PM

    "For now, higher prices are causing dramatic increases in profits of legacy oil, not the collapse that climate financial risk advocates predicted. Econ 101 works. But it is worth pointing out that the carbon tax and 'Putin's price hike' are economically identical, so experience of one can inform the other, and complaining about one is a bit silly if one enthusiastically endorses the other."

    This final part feels not entirely fair, as 'Putin's price hike' naturally benefits all (non-Russian) fuel producers, while a tax would indeed hurt them and therefore naturally be more of a risk to the industry.

    Obviously, this does not mean that the general line of the post isn't spot on and as usual nicely put, thanks a lot for the good writing on the topic!

    ReplyDelete
  10. Carbon taxes can be introduced as fiscally neutral, although they are usually thought to be regressive. They are not introduced with the intent of being a way to raise gross revenue, or as long term source of income. What they are intended to do is to stimulate investment in alternative technologies which are more carbon efficient, and to abandon/write down carbon intesive capital. Forcing people to move along the marginal abatement curve. Generally, this means less consumption and consumption growth. This in turn produces lower real rates, but higher inflation and nominal rates. Nordhaus articulated this decades ago. I really dont understand why most people working in this space, insist on going through output. Think about it - investment is 10 times more volatile than consumption. So GDP volatility volatility should increase, but level can stay on trend.

    ReplyDelete
  11. Putins price hike and carbon taxes are not identical. In the first case, profits goes to share holders in big oil, in the second case the revenue flows to governments. This is why raising the cost of carbon intensive capital (through market mechanisms or regulatory requirements) is not the best solution. It might reduce overall supply, but the profits keep flowing. In fact profit per unit of pollution increases.

    ReplyDelete

Comments are welcome. Keep it short, polite, and on topic.

Thanks to a few abusers I am now moderating comments. I welcome thoughtful disagreement. I will block comments with insulting or abusive language. I'm also blocking totally inane comments. Try to make some sense. I am much more likely to allow critical comments if you have the honesty and courage to use your real name.