"Some have argued that the presence of PTIEs could play an important role in raising deposit rates offered by banks to their retail depositors. The potential for rates offered by PTIEs to have a meaningful impact on retail deposit rates, however, seems very low...retail deposit accounts have long paid rates of interest far below those offered on money market investments, reflecting factors such as bank costs in managing such retail accounts and the willingness of retail customers to forgo some interest on deposits for the perceived convenience or safety of maintaining balances at a bank rather than in a money market investment.Here is some data. From "The Deposits Channel of Monetary Policy" by Itamar Drechsler Alexi Savov and Philipp Schnabl, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132 (2017)1819–1876:
When the Fed Funds rate rises, checking account rates do not. (It's interesting that savings and time deposits do move more quickly, indicating banks face more competition there.) The Fed's story that the spread between checking account rates and federal funds (now IOER) rates reflects costs is very hard to square with this graph -- why should costs and benefits of checking accounts change over time so much, and coincidentally rise exactly one for one with the Federal Funds rate?
Pablo Kurlat, Deposit Spreads and the Welfare Cost of Inflation plots similar data cross sectionally, which lets you estimate the pass through rate better at the expense of the time pattern:
Pablo puts the spread between deposit and federal funds rate on the vertical axis. So, if banks passed through interest rates one for one, the line would be flat. If there were a constant cost, it would be flat but at a higher level. If banks pay the same lousy rate no matter what interest rates are, the curve lies on the 45 degree line. You can see the same general picture.
(Pablo's paper is very nice. He concludes that therefore the "Friedman rule" that interest rates should perpetually be zero, with slight deflation making real rates positive, has yet another thing going for it, that banks are not able to use their market power against us so much.)
Pablo also plots data from different countries:
It's interesting that Sweden and Italy have flatter (more competitive lines). It's really interesting that Argentina lies on the 45 degree line, with no pass through, despite huge inflation-induced interest rates. I would guess that Argentina has a law against paying interest rate on deposits, as the US used to have.
No, it strikes me we have exactly what it seems to be, looking out the window, a heavily regulated not very competitive oligopoly, sort of like airlines 1972.
"He concludes that therefore the "Friedman rule" that interest rates should perpetually be zero, with slight deflation making real rates positive,"
ReplyDelete---
Zero is not a rate, he means operate at the short end of the curve making the central bank the fastest guy on the block. Prices are neutral, productivity gain becomes a monetary loss by the central bank. Interest charges will be random slightly about zero as there is no time at zero, so central bank interest charges must be asynchronous, and innovations suddenly revealed. This is all equivalent to open money market operations between a representative sample of depositors and borrowers, of equal risk with the central bank as market maker. Which is what Milt wanted,.
Working in a Danish Bank, where we now have had negative rates for around six years, I can come with this observation:
ReplyDeleteThe CB rate is minus 0.65%, but for most clients the deposit rate is 0.00%.
The banks keeps the rate at 0.00%, because the backlash of negative rates would be too bid.
For large clients (Corporates primarily) the rate on deposits is negative.