(Note: This post uses mathjax equations. If you see garbled latex code, come to the original source.)
The effect of monetary policy on inflation depends crucially on fiscal policy.
In standard new-Keynesian models, of the type used throughout the Fed, ECB, and similar institutions, for the central bank to reduce inflation by raising interest rates, there must be a contemporaneous fiscal tightening. If fiscal policy does not tighten, the Fed will not lower inflation by raising interest rates.
The warning for today is obvious: Fiscal policy is on a tear, and not about to tighten any time soon no matter what central banks do. An interest rate rise might not, then, provoke the expected decline in inflation.
Here is a very stripped down model to show the point. \begin{align*} x_t & = E_t x_{t+1} - \sigma(i_t - E_t \pi_{t+1}) \\ \pi_t & = \beta E_t \pi_{t+1} + \kappa x_t \\ i_t &= \phi \pi_t + u_t \\ \Delta E_{t+1}\pi_{t+1} & = - \sum_{j=0}^\infty \rho^j \Delta E_{t+1} \tilde{s}_{t+1+j} + \sum_{j=1}^\infty \rho^j \Delta E_{t+1}(i_{t+j}-\pi_{t+1+j}) \end{align*} The first two equations are the IS and Phillips curves of a standard new-Keynesian model. The third equation is the monetary policy rule.
The fourth equation stems from the condition that the value of debt equals the present value of surpluses. This condition is also a part of the standard new-Keynesian model. We're not doing fiscal theory here. Fiscal policy is assumed to be "passive:" Surpluses adjust to whatever inflation results from monetary policy. For example, if monetary policy induces a big deflation, that raises the real value of nominal debt, so real primary surpluses must raise to pay the now larger value of the debt. Since it just determines surpluses given everything else, this equation is often omitted, or relegated to a footnote, but it is there. Today, we just look at the surpluses. Without them, the Fed's monetary policy cannot produce the inflation path it desires.
Notation: \(\Delta E_{t+1} \equiv E_{t+1}-E_t\), \(\rho\) is a constant of approximation slightly less than or equal to one, \(\tilde{s}\) is the real primary surplus relative to debt. For example, \(\tilde{s}=0.01\) means the surplus is 1% of the value of debt, or 1% of GDP at current 100% debt to GDP. The last term captures a discount rate effect. If real interest rates are higher, that lowers the present value of surpluses. Equivalently, higher real interest rates raise the interest costs in the deficit, requiring still higher primary surpluses to pay off debt. (Reference: Equation (4.23) of Fiscal Theory of the Price Level.) \(x\) is the output gap, \(\pi\) is inflation, \(s\) is the real primary surplus, \(i\) is the interest rate, and the Greek letters are parameters.
Now, suppose the Fed raises interest rates \(\{i_t\}\) following a standard AR(1). with coefficient \(\eta = 0.6\). However, there are multiple \(\{u_t\}\) which produce the same path for \(\{i_t\}\), each of which produces a different inflation path \(\{\pi_t\}\). Each of them also produces a different fiscal response \(\{s_t\}\). So, let's look for given (AR(1)) interest rate \(\{i_t\}\) path at the different possible inflation \(\{\pi_t\}\) paths, their associated monetary policy disturbance \(\{u_t\}\) and their associated fiscal underpinnings.
The top left panel shows a standard result. The interest rate in blue rises, and then returns following an AR(1). Here, the 1% interest rate rise causes a 1% inflation decline, shown in red. I use \(\eta=0.6, \sigma = 1, \kappa = 0.25, \beta = 0.95, \phi = 1.2 \) The monetary policy disturbance \(u_t\), dashed magenta. is even larger than the actual inflation rise, but \( i_t = \phi \pi_t + u_t\) and the disinflation in \(\pi_t\) bring the interest rate to a lower value.**********
Calculations. To produce the plots I write the monetary policy rule in a different form \[ i_t = i^\ast_t + \phi ( \pi_t - \pi^\ast_t) \] \[ i^\ast_t = \eta i^\ast_{t-1} + \varepsilon_t \] Then I can specify directly the interest rate AR(1) in \(i^\ast_t\), and the initial inflation in \(\pi^\ast_t\). These forms are equivalent. Indeed, I construct \( u_t = i^\ast_t - \phi \pi^\ast_t \) in order to plot it.
I use the analytical solutions for inflation given an interest rate path derived 26.4 of Fiscal Theory, \[ \pi_{t+1}=\frac{\sigma\kappa}{\lambda_{1}-\lambda_{2}}\left[ i_{t}+\sum _{j=1}^{\infty}\lambda_{1}^{-j}i_{t-j}+\sum_{j=1}^{\infty}\lambda_{2}% ^{j}E_{t+1}i_{t+j}\right] +\sum_{j=0}^{\infty}\lambda_{1}^{-j}\delta_{t+1-j}. \] \[ \lambda_{1,\ 2}=\frac{\left( 1+\beta+\sigma\kappa\right) \pm\sqrt{\left( 1+\beta+\sigma\kappa\right) ^{2}-4\beta}}{2}, \]
Matlab code:
T = 50;
sig = 1;
kap = 0.25;
eta = 0.6;
bet = 0.95;
phi = 1.2;
pi1 = [-1 -0.5 0 0.5];
lam1 = ((1+bet+sig*kap)+ ((1+bet+sig*kap)^2-4*bet)^0.5)/2;
lam2 = ((1+bet+sig*kap)- ((1+bet+sig*kap)^2-4*bet)^0.5)/2;
lam1i = lam1^(-1);
delt = pi1 - sig*kap/(lam1-lam2)*lam2/(1-lam2*eta);
tim = (0:1:T-1)';
pit = zeros(T,1);
pit(2) = sig*kap/(lam1-lam2)*lam2/(1-lam2*eta) ; % t=1
pit(3) = sig*kap/(lam1-lam2)*(1/(1-lam2*eta)) ;
for indx = 4:T;
pit(indx) = sig*kap/(lam1-lam2)*...
(eta^(indx-3)/(1-lam2*eta) + lam1i*(eta^(indx-3)-lam1i^(indx-3))/(eta-lam1i) );
end;
pim = [pit*(1+0*pi1) + [0*delt;(lam1i.^((0:T-2)')).*delt]];
it = [0; eta.^(0:1:T-2)'];
um = it*(1+0*pi1) - phi*pim;
rterm = sum(it(2:end-1,:)-pim(3:end,:));
sterm = rterm-pim(2,:);
disp('r');
disp(rterm);
disp('s');
disp(sterm);
if 0; % all together
figure;
C = colororder;
hold on
plot(tim,pim,'-r','linewidth',2);
plot(tim,um,'--m','linewidth',2);
plot(tim,it,'-b','linewidth',2);
plot(tim,0*tim,'-k')
axis([ 0 6 -inf inf])
end;
figure; % 4 panel plot
for indx = 1:4;
subplot(2,2,indx);
hold on;
plot(tim,pim(:,indx),'-r','linewidth',2);
if indx == 1;
text(1.8,-0.7,'\pi','color','r','fontsize',18)
text(1,0.7,'i','color','b','fontsize',18);
text(2.4,1,'u','color','m','fontsize',18)
end
plot(tim,um(:,indx),'--m','linewidth',2);
plot(tim,it,'-b','linewidth',2);
plot(tim,0*tim,'-k')
title(['\Sigma s = ' num2str(sterm(indx),'%4.2f')],'fontsize',16)
axis([ 0 6 -1 1.5])
end
if eta == 0.6
print -dpng nk_fiscal_1.png
end
If I respond, will it just get me banned for being uninformed, irresponsible, or motivated by unworthy interests?
ReplyDeleteFirst, where is your key to the variables? Aren't you willfully contributing to ambiguity by listing equations without defining the variables in the same place?
Second, aren't you completely leaving out finance? Isn't government debt priced by markets without regard to unobservable surpluses? Don't banks create money to trade government debt, so that the debt takes on a market value that has far more to do with funding plumbing than this notional "surplus" you assume and never bother to actually measure?
How can you leave out finance? Don't financial flows measurably eclipse real flows by at least an order of magnitude?
When you include a properly scaled financial sector as in https://www.bis.org/publ/work890.htm (a BIS DSGE model), do you find that real goods flows are too small to influence prices?
Can you respond to Fischer Black in "Noise"?
"I think that the price level and rate of inflation are literally indeterminate. They are whatever people think they will be. They are determined by expectations, but expectations follow no rational rules. If people believe that certain changes in the money stock will cause changes in the rate of inflation, that may well happen, because their expectations will be built into their long term contracts."
John has a tendency to be expert level. The key is that he told you what each equation was so you can find it in most advance macro textbooks (or in earlier posts). The IS curve relates output (xt) to expected output and an intertemporal elasticity of substitution (sigma) discounted real interest rate ( nominal rate (i) less expected inflation (pi)). The new keynesian phillips curve relates inflation (pi) to expected inflation and output (xt) with k being the slope of the phillips curve under stable inflation expectations i think. Next he gives the monetary policy or taylor rule which describes central bank behavior setting the interest rate (i) as a function of expected inflation and random shocks to the economy (u). The parameter phi is usually taken to be greater than one such that the fed tends to overreact and thereby induce stability. The final equation is John’s labor of love which is one of several forms of an equilibrium condition relating today’s change in inflation rate to the discounted stream (or present value) of changes in future government surpluses (s) and discounted stream of changes in real interest rates. As simple as can be really ;)
DeleteBased on the code provided at the end of the post, which variables do you need defined? You can certainly quibble with the assumptions, but the terms and their values seem straightforward.
DeleteRSM,
Delete"I think that the price level and rate of inflation are literally indeterminate. They are whatever people think they will be. They are determined by expectations, but expectations follow no rational rules."
Inflation is in large part determined by productivity defined as Real GDP / Total Debt Outstanding. How much real growth can you get out of an economy for a given amount of total debt?
The inflation expectations leads to higher inflation argument falls flat and is based on some bad logic.
If I were expecting inflation in the price of hammers, would I as a carpenter run out and buy a couple hundred hammers above and beyond what I ever intend to use? There is a utilitarian aspect to consider.
If I were expecting inflation in the price of new bread, would I go out and purchase a couple of hundred loaves of bread recognizing that most the bread will turn to mold before I get a chance to eat it? There is a depreciation aspect to consider.
If I were expecting inflation in price of garbage collection or electricity, would I accelerate or decelerate my generation of garbage and use of electricity? There is a conservation factor to consider.
And that is just the spending decision. I could with elevated inflation expectations decide to pay down debts, I could decide facing elevated inflation expectations to invest in a productive enterprise, I could make numerous other decisions regarding how to allocate money that would not track with inflation expectations leading to higher demand or price inflation.
@LAL
DeleteDo you have some reading recommendations?
You can find John’s book on the Fiscal Theory if the price level in his website. Along with his Time Series and Asset Pricing books they are my favorite. But specifically for new Keynesianism Romer’s Advanced Macroeconomics textbook, Woodford’s Interest and Prices (this I think is what John uses), or maybe Mankiw. Alternativley, you can get it from lots of papers: Smets-Wouters is what John’s colleague Harald Uhlig would teach undergrads at the univeristy of Chicago. Olivier Blanchard’s papers on monopolistic price setting and John Taylor and Calvo’s papers on staggered wage settings I would say form the core of the micro foundations. (Taylor’s papers again for monetary policy rules). Most papers by Mankiw are well written, and his New Keynesian Manifesto is heart warming.
Delete》 If I were expecting inflation in the price of hammers, would I as a carpenter run out and buy a couple hundred hammers above and beyond what I ever intend to use? There is a utilitarian aspect to consider.
DeleteWhy not buy out-the-money call options on hammers? If they go in-the-money can't you just sell the option and never even handle physical hammers?
Why do you ignore finance completely, when financial stocks and flows eclipse their real counterparts by at least a factor of ten?
Did you even look at the BIS DSGE model i cited?
"Why not buy out-the-money call options on hammers? If they go in-the-money can't you just sell the option and never even handle physical hammers?"
DeleteBecause I am a carpenter, not a financial contract trader. (I thought that point was already established).
"Why do you ignore finance completely, when financial stocks and flows eclipse their real counterparts by at least a factor of ten?"
I don't ignore finance and yes I looked at the model. My response was in regard to your Fisher Black reference:
"I think that the price level and rate of inflation are literally indeterminate. They are whatever people think they will be. They are determined by expectations, but expectations follow no rational rules."
Elevated inflation expectations are not a sufficient condition to drive inflation and the price level higher.
If you can point to where inflation expectations are discussed in the paper and how they feed through to realized inflation, I would be happy to take a second look.
Also i forgot to plug John’s upcoming Fiscal Theory of the Price Level book which goes through all of this step by step in discrete and continuous time domains.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDeleteOEE,
Delete"For example, the monetary system controller, noting that the fiscal authority is over-spending and running up the debt which would be anticipated to raise inflation expectations and create supply-side shortages [ x(t) < 0, where x(t) = 1- Y(t)/Y*(t) , Y*(t) is the natural full capacity of the economy], would adjust the interest rate to immunize or cool the economy to dampen the run-up in inflation expectations."
And that adjustment of interest rates upward would create a larger interest expenditure on government debt that could in turn be spent by the public.
The Fed can't simultaneously remove bonds from circulation through open market operations (to reduce interest expenditures to the public) and raise interest rates
to "cool" the economy.
For raising interest rates to actually cool the economy, one or more of the following has to happen:
1. Government switches to zero coupon bonds (or other zero coupon securities) where interest / returns are accrued versus readily spendable.
2. Private sector credit formation must contract
And that assumes that the Ponzi limit isn't hit (total interest expenditures by government exceeds total tax revenue). At that point, bond auctions would likely fail and all bets are off.
This comment has been removed by the author.
Delete"Ponzi schemes have no limit, except when the government pounces on the operator and hauls him off to goal."
DeleteUnlike the private Ponzi operator, the federal government is fairly transparent in publishing it's income and expenditure statements, so you will need to try a little harder than that.
You really don't think bond auction participants also pay close attention to US government tax and spending policies?
John,
ReplyDelete"What if Congress looks at that and just laughs? Well, the Fed must do something else."
Congress is just one of the three branches of US Government. There is also the Executive Branch (Presidency, IRS, Treasury Department) and the Judicial Branch (court system).
Prior to Federal Reserve Act of 1913, economic policy on the national level was handled through the US Treasury Department.
"In standard new-Keynesian models, of the type used throughout the Fed, ECB, and similar institutions, for the central bank to reduce inflation by raising interest rates, there must be a contemporaneous fiscal tightening. If fiscal policy does not tighten, the Fed will not lower inflation by raising interest rates."
ReplyDeleteDoes the Fed really believe this? Do they operate under the assumption that no amount of the interest rate rising will do a thing to inflation if there is 0 Fiscal coordination?
I know this makes a lot of logical sense, especially for countries like Zimbabwe. But I get sense that the mainstream views the US as a pretty special case where fiscal policy doesn't really matter currently.
James,
DeleteIt is a little bit more complex than that.
Enough interest rate raising will either:
1. Force fiscal coordination
Or 2. Cause government bond auctions to fail
At 27 Trillion Dollars + in US debt, interest rates across all maturities of government debt need only rise to about 8% before all available tax revenue is used making interest payments (the Ponzi limit). After that point, government bond buyers are putting their own long positions at risk by buying any more government debt.
The consideration is this - if excess government spending is the root cause of higher inflation, then does it really matter how that spending manifests itself whether that spending takes the form of government wages, entitlement benefits, or even government bond interest payments?
@Frank
DeleteI think the it might, as Japan has shown. If domestic pension holders are just going to park that money in safes, while foreign bond holders will buy consumer good, then you might see two different inflation results.
James,
DeleteBut in Japan is that a cultural thing or is it a government policy that keeps it's interest payments from creating a self loop re-inforcing loop of higher inflation leading to higher interest payments leading to even higher inflation?
What I mean is that there is more than one way to kill the inflation cat. Nixon implemented price controls back in the 1970's for instance. What inflation containment measures does the government and / or bank of Japan engage in beyond changes in interest rates?
Does Japan institute automatic government spending cuts on other services when / if inflation ever becomes problematic?
On the latest version of the Fiscal Theory, abailable in John's website, the path 26.4 is something completely different. Which makes the last equation of the note, used to build the matlab code, kind of a cipher. And that has nothing to do with the "expert level" of the note.
ReplyDeleteIt took me a while to find. But derivation of the last equation of the note is actually equation (25.21) (not 26.4) in the Fiscal Theory draft available at John's website. It's on the book's appendix.
Delete